Examlex
C. L. Stevenson: The Emotive Meaning of Ethical Terms
Stevenson claims that before we can hope to answer ethical questions, we must first try to understand exactly what is being asked. In light of this, he examines the question: what does it mean to call something good? According to interest theories, to say that something is good is simply to say that it is approved of or desired, either by the speaker or by some group of people. Stevenson denies that such theories can fully capture what it means to call something good, and sets out to provide a more satisfying theory. He claims that any such theory must account for three things: (i) people may sensibly disagree about what is good, (ii) goodness has a "magnetism" in that judgments about goodness motivate us to act, and (iii) claims about goodness are not empirically verifiable. Stevenson believes his theory, emotivism, meets these requirements. According to emotivism, ethical claims are not simply attempts to describe the world, but are primarily used to influence others. As Stevenson puts the point, "ethical terms are instruments used in the complicated interplay and readjustment of human interests."
Stevenson maintains that ethical terms have emotive meanings, in the sense that they tend to produce affective responses in people. We use these emotive meanings to try to influence others to approve or disapprove of certain things. Thus, on Stevenson's view, to claim that something is good is both to express one's own approval of the thing, as well as to encourage one's audience to join in approving of it. Moral disagreements are therefore not mere disagreements in belief, in which one person believes a proposition and the other one disbelieves it. Rather, in ethical disagreements, one person has a favorable attitude toward something, whereas the other has an unfavorable attitude, and neither is content to let the other's attitude remain.
-Stevenson's primary aim is to:
Perfectly Competitive Firms
Perfectly Competitive Firms operate in a market where numerous buyers and sellers exchange homogeneous products, with no single entity able to influence the market price.
Average Variable Cost Curve
A graphical representation showing how average variable cost changes with changes in output.
Upward-sloping
Describes a line or curve on a graph that indicates an increase in a variable (e.g., price) as another variable (e.g., quantity) increases, typical of supply curves in economics.
Short Run Supply Curve
A graph showing the relationship between the market price of a product and the quantity of it that a firm is willing to supply, assuming some inputs are fixed.
Q4: Nagel claims that the problem of moral
Q6: Hobbes claims that the first law of
Q8: Williams claims that it would clearly be
Q12: Dewey maintains that there is a sharp
Q18: What is moral luck? Why didn't Kant
Q22: According to Moore, the most important sense
Q24: Cicero claims that our moral obligations are
Q24: Nagel claims that moral luck is a
Q28: According to Nagel, we tend to feel
Q32: Foot maintains modern philosophers take moral judgments